From Williams’s thesis to Williams Thesis. An anti-colonial trajectory1



Download 142.5 Kb.
Page1/3
Date16.01.2018
Size142.5 Kb.
#36530
  1   2   3
From Williams’s thesis to Williams Thesis. An anti-colonial trajectory1

Review essay of Eric Williams, The economic aspect of the Abolition of the West Indian slave trade and slavery. Edited by Dale W. Tomich (Lanham etc. 2014)

Pepijn Brandon

Senior Researcher, International Institute of Social History / Assistant Professor, VU Amsterdam

pepijn.brandon@iisg.nl

Correspondence Address: IISG / Cruquiusweg 31 / 1019 AT Amsterdam / The Netherlands / pepijn.brandon@iisg.nl

Eric Williams’s Capitalism and Slavery, published in 1944, belongs to the most influential and controversial historical studies of the twentieth century.2 The relatively short book firmly attached the name of its author to key debates over the connections between capitalist development, slavery, the slave trade, abolitionism and the roots of racism – topics that recently have re-emerged in quite remarkable fashion.3 This fact in itself would make the publication of Williams’ dissertation The Economic Aspect of the Abolition of the West Indian Slave Trade and Slavery of historiographical interest. The thesis, defended by Williams at Oxford in 1938, provided the template from which Capitalism and Slavery would be developed. However, the final text diverged in important aspects from the first draft, from which even the signature concept ‘capitalism’ is absent. As editor Dale Tomich argues in his preface to the text, the differences between the dissertation and the book can provide new insights into the intellectual sources, evolution, and theoretical directions of Williams’s work.4 This might be true for any urtext of a later classic. But it is particularly relevant to understanding the trajectory of Eric Williams, whose style has been described as ‘elusive’, saddling the debate he lent his name to with great problems of interpretation.5 The fact that Williams’s previously hard to access doctoral thesis is now available to the general public will help to clarify important aspects of the ‘Williams Thesis’ and its genesis.

The significance of The Economic Aspect, however, is not confined to mere historiography. Williams ends Capitalism and Slavery on an uncharacteristic note of modesty: ‘The historians neither make nor guide history. Their share in such is usually so small as to be almost negligible.’6 Williams’s own share however was not.7 In fact, the very years in which he reworked his dissertation into the published book saw his emergence as a leading Caribbean intellectual figure, and in political terms were crowned by the British government’s grudging acceptance of Williams as a member of the Anglo-American Caribbean Commission discussing the future of the region.8 As one historian of Trinidadian decolonization notes, Williams’s authority ‘was the deus ex machina which propelled the independence movement forward, revolutionized the political life of the colony almost overnight, and shattered the complacency of the sputtering transition to self-government.’9 Capitalism and Slavery established Williams’s status as a prominent thinker and actor in the de-colonization movement, ushering in his appointment in 1962 as the first Prime Minister of independent Trinidad and Tobago. The network in which Williams operated during his period of political and intellectual formation included the Trinidadian far left thinkers and organizers George Padmore and C.L.R. James, the African American academics Ralph Bunche, Alain Locke and Abram Harris, and scholars from the wider Caribbean such as the Cuban historian Fernando Ortiz.10 In the six years between his dissertation defense and the publication of Capitalism and Slavery, Williams published the short book The Negro in the Caribbean, in which he used the history of slavery as the starting point for a blistering condemnation of the results of political and economic dependency, as well as a flurry of articles on British colonialism in the Caribbean.11 The route from dissertation to final text runs parallel to Williams’s trajectory from a young black student combatting racism and imperial narratives at Oxford, to the future prime minister of an independent nation.



Williams’ dissertation therefore, apart from an important historiographical document also is a historical source in its own right. In this article I will examine both aspects of the text. I will use The Economic Aspect to present a reconsideration of the ‘original content’ of the Williams Thesis, the intellectual influences that went into it, and the way in which Williams’s political engagement in the years 1938-1944 influenced its finished form. Though the article does not deal with the Williams Debate that followed the publication of Capitalism and Slavery, reconsidering the ‘making of’ the Williams Thesis can have a profound impact on how we view its later interpretations and current relevance.

  1. The Economic Aspect and Capitalism and Slavery compared

For readers familiar with Capitalism and Slavery and the heated debates it produced, reading Williams’s dissertation must feel like watching the X-rays of a famous painting. Underneath the all too familiar surface, we find the old master’s original pencil sketch. While the sketch clearly depicts the same theme as the finished work, using the same cast of figures, and showing the unmistakable traits of the master’s hand, we see a completely different composition. Some of the key protagonists are missing, some attributes have been greatly enlarged while others have been moved into the background. To make the differences understandable, it is necessary to start from the finished work, Capitalism and Slavery. The book is chiefly famous for establishing two large theses. The first thesis linked the growth of capitalism in Britain in the eighteenth century to slavery and the slave trade (for the purpose of this article: Thesis I). The second held that the abolition of the transatlantic slave trade in 1807 and of slavery in the British West Indies in 1834 can be explained from the declining economic importance of the Caribbean colonies to the emerging industrial capitalism of the age (Thesis II).12 Williams was not the first to advance either of these claims.13 But he was the first to bring them together in a comprehensive study based on original source material, and he provided powerful and original arguments for both. His work was also more wide-ranging than its immediate predecessors, containing many observations on both the very local and the global impact of slavery, philosophical statements on the role of economic forces in history, and the important argument that slavery was the cause of racism, not its effect. The latter point, to which most of the first Chapter of Capitalism and Slavery was devoted, sparked an entire historiographical debate of its own.14 It has rightly been viewed as a separate Williams Thesis (Thesis III), but for reasons of space cannot be discussed extensively here. However, as we shall see in the final section of this article, the inclusion of Thesis III in Capitalism and Slavery was significant for the overall trajectory of Williams’s thinking.

Capitalism and Slavery has proven to be fertile ground for further investigation. However it has also bequeathed the ensuing ‘Williams debate’ with real problems. As the late Barbara Solow has argued: ‘Part of the difficulty in dealing with Capitalism and Slavery arises because it is not precisely clear what the Williams thesis is’.15 Throughout the book, Williams slides between ‘strong versions’ and ‘weak versions’ of Thesis I and II. On the far end of this bandwidth stands a theory of direct causation, in which slavery and the slave-trade were the most important sector on which British industrial capitalism was built, and in which the successes of abolitionism were the product of an absolute incompatibility between slavery and modern industrial capitalism. But other formulations by Williams point towards weaker versions for both theses, asserting that slavery supplied just one significant element of the funds for the industrial revolution, and that a combination of structural and conjectural economic factors merely created the circumstances under which abolitionism could be successful.16 The difficulty thus created is compounded by the argumentative structure of the text. In his preface to the book, Williams describes it as ‘strictly an economic study of the role of Negro slavery and the slave trade’.17 However, in reality the content of his study is far from straightforward. Under the broad rubric of ‘economic forces’, Capitalism and Slavery alternatingly refers to very different elements and processes, the connections between which he never fully explains theoretically or proves empirically.18 These include, but are not limited to:

a) an alleged structural tendency in slave-based sugar production to over-exploit land and labour;

b) conjectural shifts in international trade leading to a decline in the competitiveness of the British West Indies;

c) political conflicts between industrialists and old commercial interests over free trade and protectionism;

d) an anti-mercantilist and free-labour ideology emanating from political economists such as Adam Smith and Arthur Young.

All of these four, operating at essentially different levels of determination, at some point in the book are invoked as the ‘economic interests’ driving slavery’s changing relationship to capitalism.19 Of these four different directions, the first two are the most measurable in purely quantitative terms. It is here that economic historians challenging the Williams Thesis have mainly concentrated their fire.20 As a result, the Williams Thesis has become almost synonymous to the ‘decline thesis’ of West-Indian sugar production, moving debates over Capitalism and Slavery onto considerably more narrow terrain than the one sought by its author. The ‘appropriation’ of the Williams Debate by quantitative economic history has pushed Williams’s arguments on inter-capitalist conflicts between free-traders and mercantilists into the background as one of the lesser aspects of his thought. The question of ‘ideology’ was later reintroduced into the Williams Debate, concentrating on possible links between capitalism and the rise of humanitarian sensibilities rather than on economic policy. This was perceived as a move away from Williams’ ‘strictly economic approach’.21 Furthermore, economic historians tended to argue for or against Williams’s assertion of the declining profitability of sugar within a largely bilateral framework focused solely on Britain and its imperial connections.22

Based on Capitalism and Slavery alone, it is hard to tell what weight to give to the various factors enlisted by Williams. It is here that the publication of The Economic Aspect can prove particularly useful. Both Dale Tomich and David Beck Ryden have argued that in his dissertation, Williams formulates his arguments more coherently, in a less linear fashion, and with a considerably different emphasis than in the later text.23 The greater coherence in presentation is partly due to the choice made by Williams to cover a much more limited subject and time-frame. The twelve chapters and three appendices of the dissertation only extensively cover the period from 1783, the year in which the first petition for the abolition of the slave trade was presented to the British Parliament, to 1833, the year Parliament accepted the Slavery Abolition Act. As these dates suggest, the thesis focusses entirely on the contribution of economic factors to the abolition of the slave trade and slavery, and leaves out the question of the contribution made by slavery to the development of British capitalism in its earlier phase. In fact, perhaps astonishingly, the word ‘capitalism’ is not mentioned anywhere in the dissertation. Although the course of the argument makes it quite clear that Williams thought about his problem in broad systemic terms, he chose to present his findings in the more modest language of ‘economic aspects’ that led to slavery becoming considered ‘impolitic’ by leading sections of the British ruling class.24

Each of the four levels of economic determination described above can be found in some form in the dissertation. But unlike in Capitalism and Slavery, the mode of presentation makes it possible to attach weight and direction to these factors. With a clear focus on the economic arguments involved in the parliamentary debates on abolition and emancipation, and a chronology that revolves around the key turning points in these debates, much more space is allowed for the contingent ways in which structural problems, shifts in international trade, rising free-trade ideologies and even humanitarian movements came together at different moments. This does not so much lead to a change of outcome, but one of emphasis between the two texts. In The Economic Aspect, the humanitarianism of the abolitionists is not completely dismissed as a fig leaf for purely material interests. Rather, with considerable attention to the utterances of leading abolitionists themselves, Williams sets out to show the changes in the ‘economic atmosphere’ that determined to what extent ‘noble ideas and elevated sentiments’ could exert decisive influence on policy.25 Furthermore, the driving force of economic change did not stem directly from the ebbs and flows of Caribbean sugar production, but from an empire-wide crisis of mercantilist economic policies that stimulated the rise of powerful domestic reform movements, tying the question of slavery to more general campaigns over free trade, the corn laws, and parliamentary reform. The ‘decline’ of the British West-Indies only attains its definitive meaning within this larger context.26

Williams’ narrative in The Economic Aspect foregrounds international and comparative aspects. The pivotal moments sealing the fate of the British Caribbean slave complex and mercantilist trade policies alike were the American Revolution, the failure of the British state to definitively conquer the French colonies after the Haitian Revolution, and the rise of new sugar producing centers in Cuba, Brazil and East India. To be clear, these international events and processes would remain highly significant to Williams’s argument in Capitalism and Slavery. But the mode of presentation in the latter work seemingly privileges bi-lateral connections between Britain and its colonies. In Capitalism and Slavery, apart from the American Revolution that fills the crucial chapter 6, international events are treated in relatively brief sections as part of chapters that principally revolve around developments, groups and classes in Britain (‘British Capitalism’, the ‘commercial part of the nation’, ‘the saints’). In contrast, eight out of the twelve chapters of The Economic Aspect have international comparative aspects or geopolitical conflicts at their core.27 More than in Capitalism and Slavery, Williams in his dissertation explains the debates between capitalists and policy-makers as a result of the changing comparative weight of competing slave-systems, geopolitics and international diplomacy, and conflicting visions of the ‘national interest’. This also translates into the conclusions of the dissertation, which are much more open-ended than those of the book. The difference in emphasis can be seen most clearly in comparing the two versions of Williams’ final reflections on the Abolition Act of 1833. In Capitalism and Slavery, Williams ends the penultimate chapter on the following triumphant note: ‘In 1833, therefore, the alternatives were clear: emancipation from above, or emancipation from below. But EMANCIPATION. … The Negroes had been stimulated to freedom by the development of the very wealth which their labor had created.’28 The Economic Aspect ends much more soberly, closer in fact to modern discussions on the ‘second slavery’ than to debates over the ‘decline thesis’:

‘The West Indians were thrown overboard, but slavery was not thereby abolished all over the world. In fact slavery and the slave trade increased and we give a false view of the emancipation movement if we do not present it in its proper context as part of the struggle of the industrial and commercial classes against monopolies. What gaps were left by the abolition of slavery in the West Indies would be filled up by the slave labourers of Brazil, Cuba, and the United States.’29

Thus, in important respects, The Economic Aspect runs against standard interpretations of the Williams Thesis that have shaped debates over capitalism and slavery for over seven decades. To understand why Capitalism and Slavery became such a different book from the original draft, it is first necessary to situate the dissertation.



  1. Adversaries, sources and influences

Eric Williams entered Oxford University in 1932 as a man of barely twenty-one years of age, after having obtained a prestigious Island Scholarship in his native Trinidad. After completing his undergraduate studies as first of his class, he unsuccessfully tried to enter All Souls College. In his autobiography Williams describes the negative impact of institutional racism on his chances of getting into this prestigious college.30 In the end, he decided to continue his studies in history, defending his PhD-thesis in 1938. Vincent Harlow, writer of a study on the seventeenth-century colonization of Barbados, acted as his supervisor. Reginald Coupland sat on his committee. After graduating, Coupland would become the target of Williams’s most bitter recriminations against the imperial school of British historiography. As he would later remark:

‘Coupland’s historical writings carry on the tradition of British historiography as established in the nineteenth century …, sharpening this tradition in order to face the increasing criticism to which imperialism was subjected. The core of his doctrine is his analysis of the abolition movement as a successful humanitarian crusade.’31

Although Williams did not challenge Coupland directly in his dissertation, attacking the humanitarian interpretation was his main aim: ‘By thus giving all the credit to humanity and none to sound policy a distorted view was presented which it is the purpose of this thesis to correct.’32 Both Darity and Garcia Muñiz demonstrate the pressure that his supervisor Vincent Harlow exerted on Williams to mollify his treatment of the humanitarian school.33 In the version of the dissertation defended before the committee Williams made some concessions to the influence of humanitarianism, but left the thrust of his argument fully intact.

Given this overarching aim to challenge imperial historiography, it is unsurprising that Williams sought battle with the humanitarian school on its own terrain. It is worthwhile to notice that the introduction of The Economic Aspect does not present the text as ‘strictly an economic study’, but rather as a study of economic motives and the way they influenced the course of political debate.34 Williams employs economic statistics to show that the shifting terms in British debates were based on ‘real’ material changes.35 But the figures everywhere are supportive of a main narrative that focuses on arguments drawn from Parliamentary debates, the writings and letters of leading abolitionists, and diplomatic papers – the type of material that was also used by the political historians he criticized.36 This approach points towards an important intermediary step between ‘economic forces’ and policy, that is sometimes missing from Capitalism and Slavery. The ‘impolicy’ of the slave trade and later slavery became a crucial weapon in the abolitionists’ arsenal, because their goal was ‘to win over hostile forces thinking fundamentally in terms of economics.’37 Apart from providing a clearer view of how economic interests became translated into abolitionist policies, this line of reasoning also gives Williams some room to acknowledge that other, perhaps even humanitarian motives played a role in the struggle against slavery. Howard Temperley has gone so far as to suggest that as a result, the dissertation does not consider economic factors as dominant over humanitarianism.38 But Darity has rightly, and with acerbic wit, rejected this as selective reading on Temperley’s part.39 Many of the passages in which Williams grants humanitarianism an independent role bear the marks of having been injected as concession to his supervisor.40 Some such formulations even found their way into Capitalism and Slavery, but in neither of the two texts Williams compromised on his key points; that the humanitarian sentiments of the leading abolitionists were circumscribed and held in check by economic interests, and that the abolitionists’ ability to influence power remained dependent on economic circumstances throughout.41

The question of the intellectual precedents for Williams’ rejection of the humanitarian school proves harder to solve than it would seem at first glance. Whether it was out of awareness of his precarious position within a white and elitist academic environment, or stemming from a wish to underline his intellectual independence, Williams remained highly idiosyncratic in his choices to reveal or conceal his influences. William Darity has suggested that ‘major aspects of Williams’ argument concerning the causes of British abolition were present in prominent texts in British economic history in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries despite Williams’ lack of acknowledgement.’42 He further suggests that rivalry between Oxford and Cambridge might have led to Williams’s omissions in this regard.43 Instead, already in the dissertation Williams foregrounds the work of one North-American scholar in particular, Lowell Joseph Ragatz. In the annotated list of secondary sources, he praises Ragatz’s ‘monumental’ bibliographical work, and also singles out his The Fall of the Planter Class in the British Caribbean as ‘easily the best work on the period’.44 Few years later, Ragatz would become Williams’ academic liaison with the University of North Carolina Press, the publisher of Capitalism and Slavery. Williams even dedicated the book to him. For these reasons, it is not surprising that many have seen Ragatz as a major influence on the formulation of Williams’ thesis. But some caution is warranted. Both in his dissertation and in Capitalism and Slavery, Williams made copious use of the statistical information gathered by Ragatz. These statistics helped to show that in 1790 ‘that grand edifice, the old plantation system in the British West Indies, was tottering from structural weakness.’45 However, the other central link in Williams’s economic reasoning – that the collapse of the West Indian sugar economies was a manifestation of a crisis of the mercantilist system of colonial trade – is not of great importance to Ragatz. What is more, Ragatz and Williams are completely at odds in their explanation of abolitionism. In both his chapter on abolition and that on emancipation, Ragatz presents the movement as ‘the most signal triumphs of the new humanitarianism’ over vested interests.46

If there is a real candidate for having launched elements of the Williams Thesis before Williams, it is a very different author who Williams praises in The Economic Aspect, but who completely vanished from Capitalism and Slavery and after that went fully unnoticed. This author is the German economist Franz Hochstetter, who in 1905 published a short book called Die wirtschaftlichen und politischen Motive für die Abschaffung des britischen Sklavenhandels im Jahre 1806/1807.47 As the title suggests, it only covers the theme of half of Williams’ dissertation, leaving out the entire period from the abolition of the slave trade to the emancipation of the slaves in the British West Indies. Hochstetter’s racialized notions of moral and cultural development were starkly at odds with Williams’ inclinations.48 Nevertheless, in the way Hochstetter constructs his argument that economic reasoning lay behind the abolition of the slave trade, there is a direct line to The Economic Aspect. Rejecting the ‘extreme Liberalism’ of the British historical school49, Hochstetter argued:



Download 142.5 Kb.

Share with your friends:
  1   2   3




The database is protected by copyright ©ua.originaldll.com 2024
send message

    Main page